The outlook for the mining industry
Eoin Treacy's view His commentary focused on the reliability of reserve estimates. He made the
point that these calculations do not reflect economic considerations. New technology
can increase reserve life and higher commodity prices can make previously uneconomic
reserves viable once more. Therefore it is misleading to talk about mine reserves
without taking these additional factors into consideration.
He also
pointed out that most mining booms end because supply begins to exceed demand
rather than demand dwindling. In the last 10 years miners have been cautious
about bringing new supply online and have managed to attain progressively higher
prices for their respective commodities. However, a number of the larger miners
have plans to open significant new operations over the medium-term which will
result in a substantial boost to aggregate supply. Rio Tinto's plan for a massive
iron-ore mine in Guinea is an example. (Also see Comment of the Day on March
22nd). In light of this development I asked the subscriber concerned for
his opinion which he kindly submitted. Here it is in full:
"As
for the iron ore market...here are a few thoughts.
"In
my experience, the biggest thing that turns mining booms into busts is over-supply,
even while (usually) demand continues to grow. Up until now, many commentators
have focussed on Chinese growth, and how long will it last, and how fragile
it is or isn't. Clearly if Chinese growth falters than there is an issue for
commodity suppliers. But this is not a great concern of mine.
"But
if demand grows at 10% and supply grows at more than 10%, at some point the
relative bargaining positions will change, and (if past experience is a guide)
the price impact could be very substantial. This is a concern of mine. There
is a lot of mooted supply coming on to the market. $120/tonne can quickly turn
to $50/tonne, and this would certainly take the gloss off a lot of mining stocks.
The issue is one faced by any capital intensive industry, but mining is particularly
sensitive because of the idiosyncratic nature of mining investments. Let me
explain:
"1)
If your industry cost structure is nearly all operating costs, when you have
over-supply (and the price drops) then supply is readily taken out of the market.
Supply imbalance and price dislocation resolves fairly quickly
"2)
If your industry cost structure has a high element of capital costs (cash costs
much lower than average selling price) then this resolution of supply/demand
imbalance takes longer and varies greatly across industries. For example: faced
with over-supply, airlines will discount (the costs of a marginal, otherwise
empty seat is very low) but this is a survival tactic good for only a short
time. The limit in time and sustainability of the over-supply situation meets
economic reality because a big chunk of the capital deployed (the aircraft)
can be redeployed elsewhere. The airline industry might have high capital costs,
but not too much is sunk costs because if things turn pear-shaped a relatively
high proportion of the capital value can be recovered by turning it so some
other use. Also booms in this and many other industries tend to be sectoral,
so the non-over-supplied parts of the world can happily absorb the redeployed
capital.
"3)
In the mining industry, commodities are traded across the globe, almost all
of the capital cost is a sunk cost, and prices can fall to at or below cash
costs and supply won't necessarily be taken off the market. Indeed, in the past,
price falls have often been accompanied by increases in production as under-capitalised
producers try to squeeze as much cash out of their operations as possible, exacerbating
the supply/demand imbalance. And even for the well-capitalised producers, high
closure costs and high care-and-maintenance costs mean that mines might keep
operating at below cash costs. Is this what we are facing?
"It's
a big topic, but very relevant. I have done a number of presentations recently
on this and similar issues, urging caution in bringing on too much supply, and
also suggesting that the way we go about making these investments is flawed
in that it promotes too high planned and initial production rates from new mines.
But in hot sectors (e.g. Iron ore mining, right now) this isn't information
that too many people want to hear!